рус  | eng  |

Exclusive

More people are now opting for diamonds rather than plain gold jewellery, because they offer a greater investment opportunity and are trendier
rajiv_popley_preview.jpgRajiv Popley, Director of Popley Group, is well-known in the jewellery and watch sector in Mumbai. In the year 2006, Rajiv launched the first Indian boutiques for Tag Heuer and Omega. His passion for watches and luxury led him to build trade relations with Switzerland by fostering the Indo-Swiss society. Rajiv was also one of the first few to launch platinum jewellery India in association with Platinum Guild International. He has been promoting this rare metal for over a decade. In an interview with Rough&Polished, Rajiv sees the Indian jewellery market becoming more demand-driven with the younger generation playing a major part in the future.

De Beers opens door for non-sightholder diamond businesses
lynette_gould_substitute_preview.jpgDe Beers said the proposed amendments to the group’s allocations model will involve a new method for determining Global Sightholder Sales’ rough diamond customer-base, with a simplified, compliance and demand-based customer qualification process being introduced. The group’s head of media relations Lynette Gould told Rough&Polished’s Mathew Nyaungwa in an exclusive interview that non-Sightholder diamond businesses that meet the compliance requirements, but have not demonstrated sufficient demand for primary source De Beers rough diamonds over a reference period, would be eligible to purchase the so-called Ex plan rough diamonds.

Silver Promotion Service can and should become the "Amazon" for silver jewelry – Michael Barlerin
michael_barlerin_preview.jpgSilver jewelry sales in the U.S. saw a significant increase over the last year, according to a survey recently conducted for the Silver Institute’s Silver Promotion Service (SPS) in the United States. The average increase in 2013 for silver jewelry sales was 17%, findings from the survey showed. The Silver Promotion Service is the jewelry industry’s organization for silver, with a potential to become the "Amazon" for silver jewelry. SPS Director Michael Barlerin discusses the latest trends and shares his vision for silver jewelry in an exclusive interview with Rough&Polished.

Botswana Diamonds salutes JV partner Alrosa as ‘top’ targets drilling commences Sept
Botswana Diamonds said its Sunland joint venture with the Russian diamond giant, Alrosa is proving to be fruitful. Company chairperson John Teeling told Rough & Polished’s Mathew Nyaungwa in an exclusive interview that their strategy in Orapa, Botswana would have been different had they not partnered with the Russians. He also said that apart from its partnership with Alrosa, Botswana Diamonds believed that it was operating in the right area. Teeling noted that they had “excellent” indications that there are undiscovered kimberlites in Orapa.



News

17.09.2014
Alrosa teams up with DTZ-OZGEO to prospect for Zim diamonds
Diamond giant Alrosa is set to prospect for diamonds in Zimbabwe with DTZ-OZGEO, a Zimbabwe-Russia joint venture company.

17.09.2014
Finance Ministry of Russia suggests to double spending on purchase of precious metals and stones to Gokhran
Russia's Finance Ministry  suggests to double spending on purchase of precious metals and stones to Gokhran in 2015-2016.

17.09.2014
Accreditation for the 2nd Edition of International Jewellery Economic Forum taking place in Moscow on September 29 - October 1 is open
Accreditation for the three days of the 2nd International Jewellery Economic Forum has started. The event will take place in the Congress Center of the Chamber of Commerce and Industry in Moscow.



Major Trend on Diamond Market

03.07.2008

The abrupt jump in prices for large-size and high-quality rough diamonds has triggered heated polemics in the professional medium. Key mining companies’ representatives point to the following unbiased reasons: the necessity to switch over to underground mining substantially contributing to cost increase and the shrinking share of high-quality rough in the current mining pattern due to depletion of major primary deposits. Both factors are essentially recognized by opponents from the cutting industry, but the price growth rate is causing bewilderment in this camp, to say the least – on the background of utterly weak current jewelry markets in the U.S.A., Japan and Europe, an adequate price rise for polished diamonds looks unlikely and expensive rough will make the industry work “for the inventory,” which may result in crucial losses.

Is the June price leap amplitude an artifact generated by short-run subjective or possibly speculative reasons or do we face a stable trend pointing to paramount changes on the diamond market? Does the new price reflect just the cost value of underground pit construction or is it an indicator of nearing structural transformations radically changing not only the position of players but also the game rules? If we analyze the developing situation within the frames of the commonly accepted paradigm, then indeed under the circumstances of evidently long-term stagnation of jewelry markets in the countries, which happen to be major consumers of diamond jewelry, the new prices look ultra mundane and their correction may be expected soon to balance demand and supply. However, if we stick to the assumption that the rough and polished diamond markets are in their essence the markets of information products, whose use value generally does not correlate with their physical properties and price, then the result of our analysis would be quite the opposite saying that the current price leap is appropriate, no price correction is expected and what is more – prices for large-size and high-quality rough diamonds in the nearest future will be growing at the same or even higher rates.

Let us allow a slight analogy with the market of the refined information product – operating systems (OS). As is known, up to 1980 operating systems had no market of their own and the buyer purchasing a certain model of electronic data processing machine was unfailingly given an OS specially designed for this computer. In summer 1981, computer giant IBM hit the market with the world’s first personal computer along with three optional OS: UCSD Pascal designed by IBM and worth $450; CP/M-86 designed by Digital Research and worth $175; and MS-DOS developed by a small company called Microsoft and modestly worth $60. Bill Gates’ brainchild was unrivalled in terms of its cost/efficiency ratio, but it was not this circumstance, which brought him his further fantastic success. Having won the first round with the help of elementary dumping, Gates managed to convince IBM to provide the computer with an open architecture, i.e. actually to permit copying to anyone and anywhere. IBM technical reference manuals appeared on free sale at $49 per one set. However, Gates’ own operating systems were made with a closed code – unsanctioned copying and distribution in civilized countries were criminally persecuted.
As a result of this ingenuous trick Microsoft earned tens of billions of dollars and turned into the worst enemy of IBM, which lost tens of billions of dollars respectively.

This was how a market for the new information product was brought into being, and almost immediately there emerged a monopolist. From the very start, the OS price was in no way tied to the use value or to any conceivable features of this commodity whatsoever. Why UCDS Pascal was 7.5 times more expensive than MS-DOS despite their equal performance capacities and consumed resources? Why does a box containing the latest Windows version now cost $450, and not $126 or $2090? (Much the same questions about the origin of price for various diamond grades may be put to the authors of price-lists of De Beers or ALROSA. With a similar success.) These questions cannot be answered by operating the concepts of “demand,” “supply,” “profitability,” “prime cost,” etc. This is not a commodity market, but an information market, where the price of a product is determined exclusively by the seller’s capabilities to make the image of the current price in the buyer’s mind look “fair.”

In the course of fifteen years, desperate attempts of rivals (for instance, by way of OS/2 on the part of the above mentioned IBM against Windows 3.1) failed to shake the monopolistic position of Microsoft controlling over 95% of the OS market. It is hard to tell if Microsoft programmers outmatched IBM programmers, but Bill Gates’ marketing experts were downright better. However, the patriarch of the IT industry finally figured it out that the information product market differed from the commodity market not only in pricing ways, but due to an opportunity of arbitrary managing the use value, which could be assigned a zero value (the market would be wound up in this case) or even a negative value (if a commodity was harmful to the consumer). This brought about Linux – an open-code operating system permitting free copying, distribution and follow-up development. From the point of view of open-code adepts, Microsoft products have at least three “consumer harmful” features: they violate the natural human right for free access to information; they contain errors and flaws, which are intentionally concealed from the buyer; and the product price is wholly unsubstantiated. Evidently, this kind of criticism is affecting the use value of Microsoft products, but in this particular case it is not just a marketing move of yet another competitor. A much bigger thing is at stake: if there is no way to score a victory in competition on the information product market or it takes too much – find some way to kill the market and then make it up again on your own conditions.

Initially, Linux proper and the concept of producing open-source software taken as a whole were played off to public as some breakthrough of high-minded and independent professionals concerned with human rights in the field of free circulation of information. However, it was impossible to hide the truth too long: the project was financed by IBM. The “blue giant” finally found a means to make Microsoft pay the old debts. In what way is Linux different from Windows? Economically, in one point only: Windows is a commodity, which the consumer buys for money, while Linux is free of charge. It is plain as daylight that the open-source concept kills the OS market itself; otherwise what’s the use of a market for a product without price? The next step was already evident – from day to day, consumers would be offered more and more computers (Dell and some other manufacturers already joined the ranks with IBM) furnished with a free OS for which there would be continuously developed new charge-free utility software accessible through the Internet. This process is currently turning very expensive to Microsoft losing tens of billions of dollars every year and stuck in a quagmire of endless court proceedings against open-code apologists. But the outlook is altogether clear – the powerful computer “hardware” manufacturers will seize a hefty slice of the OS market from Microsoft and recover the expenditures for Linux. How many percents of the cost of new computers will this compensation amount to? And why does Windows cost $450? These questions are of one and the same nature. As for the consumer, they are rhetorical.

Let us turn back to the diamond market and view it as an information product market through the prism of the above analogy.

Before the discovery of primary diamond fields in South Africa, gem-quality diamond was an extremely rare stone, which determined its high price. After the discovery of Kimberlite pipes, it became evident that diamond is not a rarity that much and if the diamond market will operate like a regular commodity market, being geared to the balance of demand and supply, the prices will crumble and any further pricing will be of a chaotic and unruly nature. The discovery of South African diamond fields and beginning of their intensive operation was simultaneous with the crises and actual termination of the European market of noble opals – the most receptive gemstones market in that period. Whether this coincidence was incidental or not is a subject for a dedicated investigation, but the fact, that the opal market was collapsed entirely due to the spread rumors about bad luck brought by the stone to its owner and its ability to facilitate cholera infection, was unlikely to miss the attention of those who handled the diamond market structure. The opal story was a dramatic instance of how the use value of a gem may be reversed – but if this was true, it meant it was inherently wieldy. Then, if the use value may be controlled, it means we are not dealing with a commodity as such, but with its information skin, with a sui generis matrix, whose content is actually what makes the end consumer pay for it with relish (or flee from it like a lamplighter in the case of “ill-fated” opal).

The entire history of the modern diamond market may be described as a process of managing the use value. Such an approach allows explaining, for instance, the paradoxical “stretchability” of the market, when discovery and wonton development of new large diamond fields in Yakutia, Angola or Canada was not followed even by short-term price sags. Here an easy explanation may be found to the relative market “harmlessness” of any synthetics, treated stones and such marvels as “black diamonds.” That sort of effects is possible because the information skin happens to be the genuine commodity; it has not only a great number of dimensions, but also tuning bands facilitating its quick adaptation to new market realities. Thus, when in the mid-1960s the market was hit by an avalanche of small-size rough from the U.S.S.R., there appeared the “eternity ring” with 25 small diamonds for American matrons celebrating their silver weddings. The development of this vector allowed “utilization” of an enormous portion of rough without any harm to other market segments, excluding price games and, naturally, monopolistic control of Yakutia’s diamond output – just at the expense of elaborating the information model. The efficiency of adjusting the matrix to suit some situation is increasing with the lapse of time due to the development of mass communication means and perfection attained in manipulating the consumer’s awareness. Up to now, this skin was expanding and trapping more and more consumers. This sweet process has been going on for so long and managed so efficiently that all went a bit oblivious it was man-made and reversible.

The long-term expansive development of this matrix has brought the notional framework laying in its basis near to its logical abnegation. The “eternal value” has become too easily obtainable and too cheap. In what particular way a 0.3 carat “gift of love” is different from that of 3.0 carats? Of course, the latter’s price and size are greater, but what about eternity and love? Does a $50 luxury piece on the finger of a happy Chinese girl student make you gently smile? But this is a diamond, the same kind of crystalline carbon as in the necklace of a Hollywood star, only a bit smaller… Any further devaluation of the notional framework of the matrix will lead to losing control over the use value and turn the diamond market into chaos with unpredictable price formation. However, the use value reversibility is expected this time to play the role of a safeguarding device.

The tack of market re-formatting is already being clearly delineated. The familiar information skin should be related only to large-size and high-quality rough and polished diamonds. Exactly to those, which are now so rapidly gaining in price. Consequently, they are turning more expensive not only because mining companies have to recover their expenses for underground works. They are growing dearer because genuine diamonds may only go up the price ladder and “the more they are genuine, the pricier they are” – this is the beep sound of the matrix. Everything else, all those “Indian goods” are just trash, bort, pseudo diamonds, parody to diamonds fit only to make bijouterie. Do you see how genuine diamonds take on their value? Do you remember that genuine diamonds are always rising in price? While trash isn’t getting more expensive, it is even getting cheaper; these are no diamonds, no one needs them; there is an enormous speculative bubble inflated in this segment soon going busted and then such rough will be dirt-cheap; that’s it, this market will be no more!

What will happen if the use value of small rough and polished diamonds will be brought to naught? Orderly arrays of numerous petty speculators ever ready to sell the “eternal value” with a good discount will sink into non-existence. Mining companies will optimize and make cheaper beneficiation techniques dumping “Indian goods” into waste piles. There will be completed the process of establishing vertically integrated transnational holdings consolidating all the stages of diamond processing under one roof – from mining rough to retail sales of jewelry under world brands. Contradictions between mining companies, diamond cutters and speculators will be drastically removed: those diamond cutters and siteholders, which by some reason will not enter the vertically integrated holdings will soon follow the “Indian goods,” since virtually there will be no high-quality rough left on the free market. The latter will negotiate a new spiral turn, where the notional framework of the information skin will be cleared of peelings stuck in recent decades and diamond will again become an “eternal value” – a rare and fabulously pricy dream of many, but owned by the few.

Well, of course, lucky owners of genuine diamonds will have to pay through their noses. Much more than they pay today – the current price hike is only the beginning of the process. And they will do pay – since diamonds are given back their exclusivity so much valued by consumers, whose annual income exceeds a certain level. And of course, such a consumer will refrain from asking, “Why does this diamond cost just that much?”

That would be a rhetorical question.

Comments

Only registered users are allowed to comment.
Register
Sign in
© 2007-2014 Rough and Polished